Monday, June 24, 2013

Introduction Financial Crises (1620-1920). A series of installments.

Federal Reserve Bank of New York 

Liberty Street Economics 

June 24, 2013


"Crisis Chronicles:  300 Years of Financial Crises (1620-1920)."

  James Narron and David Skeie

As momentous as financial crises have been in the past century, we
sometimes forget that major financial crises have occurred
for centuries—and often. This new series chronicles mostly forgotten
financial crises over the 300 years—from 1620 to 1920—just prior to
the Great Depression.

Today, we journey back to the 1620s and take a fresh look at an
economic crisis caused by the rapid debasement of coin in the states that
made up the Holy Roman Empire.


The Kipper und Wipperzeit (1619–23)

The Kipper und Wipperzeit is the common name for the
economic crisis caused by the rapid debasement of subsidiary,
or small-denomination, coin by Holy Roman Empire states
in their efforts to finance the Thirty Years’ War (1618–48).

In a 1991 article, Charles Kindleberger—author of the earlier work  
Manias, Panics and Crashes and originally a Fed
economist—offered a fascinating account of the causes and
consequences of the 1619–23 crisis.  Kipper refers to coin clipping and
Wipperzeit refers to a see-saw (an allusion to the counterbalance scales
used to weigh species coin). Despite the clever name, two forms
of debasement actually fueled the crisis. One involved reducing the
value of silver coins by clipping shavings from them; the
other involved melting the coins, mixing them with inferior metals,
re-minting them, and returning them to circulation. As the crisis evolved, an
early example of Gresham’s Law took hold as bad money drove out
 good. As Vilar notes in A History of Gold and Money, once
 “agriculture laid down the plow” at the peak of the crisis and farmers
turned to coin clipping as a livelihood, devaluation, hyperinflation, early
forms of currency wars, and crude capital controls were either firmly
in place or not far behind.


Clipped_thaler


From Self-Sufficiency to Money and Markets

The period preceding and including the early 1600s was marked by
a fundamental shift from feudalism to capitalism, from medieval to
modern times, and from an economy driven by self-sufficiency to one driven
by markets and money. It is within this social and economic context
that various states in the Holy Roman Empire attempted to finance the
Thirty Years’ War by creating new mints and debasing subsidiary coins,
leaving large-denomination gold and silver coins substantially unaffected.

In a simple example, subsidiary coin might initially be minted using
only silver, then gradually undergo a shift in metallic content as a growing
percentage of copper was added during re-mintings, until the
monetary system was effectively on a copper rather than a gold 
or silver standard. This shift in metallic content created a divergence
 between a coin’s nominal value and its intrinsic metal value, which
led to the rapid debasement of coin. As Kindleberger notes, “Bad money was
taken by debasing states to their neighbors and exchanged for
good [money]. The neighbor typically defended itself by debasing
its own coin.”

Owing to trade and the easy circumvention of laws that forbade the
removal of coin from a city, states found that early forms of
capital controls were ineffective and that a large portion of circulating
coin originated elsewhere. Given this porosity, individual states
determined that reforming their own minted coinage by returning
to a silver standard did not necessarily allow them to reform the
currency circulating within the state. So states sought greater revenue
through seigniorage—the difference between the cost of production (including
the price of the metal contained in the coin) and the nominal value of
the coin—by minting more money and by taking debased coin
abroad, exchanging it, and bringing home good coin and re-minting it.

The rapid debasement up to 1622 created a European boom,
which turned to mania by early 1622 when average citizens turned
to coin clipping as a livelihood, then hyperinflation in 1622 and 1623.
Many became rich by exploiting the unknowing—typically peasants.
This ultimately led to a widespread breakdown in trade as
peasants, fearing that they would be paid in debased coin, refused to
bring products to market, creating the spillover to the broader economy.


Cry Up, Cry Down, or Call In


One response to the crisis was for states to “cry up” good coins
by raising the denomination or “cry down” bad coins by lowering
their denomination. Another response was to “call in” coin and re-mint
it. A third response was to enforce minting standards. But central
authority was so weak that no one state could solve the crisis without
the help and support of neighboring states. States were finally
able to solve the crisis through mint treaties and by setting exchange
rates, with hyperinflation subdued by a return to the Imperial Augsburg
Ordinance of 1559. Because the public became so wary of
clipped and debased coin, it took months to convince the masses
that coin was good once it was restored.


History Repeating Itself


Like markets and money, crises evolve easily but lessons learned
often last only a lifetime and are easily forgotten. Over the coming year,
we’ll share with you how elements of this crisis were repeated during the
Great Re-Coinage of 1696, the Mississippi Bubble of 1720,
the Dutch Commodities Crash of 1763, and the Continental Currency
Crisis of 1779, with each crisis adding a unique twist.

In the meantime, as we reflect upon the states’ struggles to manage their domestic
economies of the 1620s at a time of evolving money, markets, and trade,
and amid pressure to finance the Thirty Years’ War, we pose the
following question: Is it possible to draw any parallels
between the events of the 1620s and the current objectives of the Group
of Seven to meet “respective domestic objectives using domestic
instruments”? Tell us what you think.


Disclaimer
The views expressed in this post are those of the authors and do not
necessarily reflect the position of the Federal Reserve Bank of New
York or the Federal Reserve System. Any errors or omissions are the
responsibility of the authors.





  Narron_james
James Narron is a senior vice president in the Federal Reserve
Bank of New York's Executive Office.


  Skeie_david
David Skeie is a senior economist in the Bank's Research
and Statistics Group.


 

No comments: