Thursday, May 23, 2013

Current account deficits are easing in Italy, Greece, Spain and Portugal.

May 22, 2013


30

 

 

New York Federal Reserve Bank

Foreign Borrowing in the Euro Area Periphery: The End Is Near

Matthew Higgins and Thomas Klitgaard

Current account deficits in euro area periphery countries have now largely disappeared. This represents a substantial adjustment. Only two years ago, deficits stood at nearly 10 percent of GDP in Greece and Portugal and 5 percent in Spain and Italy (see chart below). This sharp narrowing means that spending has been brought in line with income, largely righting an imbalance that had left these countries dependent on heavy foreign borrowing. However, adjustment has come at a sizable cost to growth, with lower domestic spending only partly offset by higher export sales. Downward pressure on domestic spending should abate now that the periphery countries have been weaned from foreign borrowing. The risk, though, is that foreign creditors might demand that the countries pay down (rather than merely service) accumulated external debts, forcing them to reduce spending below incomes.

    A country’s current account balance measures how much it lends to or borrows from the rest of the world. A country where imports run ahead of exports is also spending more than it produces and must borrow abroad to make up the difference. Countries in the euro area periphery borrowed heavily from abroad during the several years leading up to the ongoing sovereign debt and banking crisis. As a result, they faced wrenching adjustment pressures when foreign investors became unwilling to extend new credit, even with the lure of sharply higher interest rates. These adjustment pressures forced changes in the balance between exports and imports, and equivalently in the balance between income and spending, without any help from an exchange rate channel because of the shared euro currency.


Periphery-Current-Account-Balances


Exports and Imports
The loss in access to foreign credit meant that export revenues had to rise relative to import purchases. As seen in the table below, much of the recent adjustment in Italy, Spain, and Portugal has come from higher export revenues. From 2010 to 2012, nominal goods and services exports in these countries rose by 15 percent or more, roughly in line with Germany’s performance. Higher exports in these countries have helped support growth, softening ongoing economic downturns. Greece, in contrast, saw export sales rise only 8 percent over this two-year period; this increase provided only limited help easing the country’s severe downturn.


Export-Sales-and-Import-Spending


    A look at the geographic breakdown of goods exports shows that the lion’s share of the increase was from sales outside the euro area, particularly to markets in North America, Asia, and oil-exporting countries. Indeed, periphery countries’ sales outside the euro area rose by roughly 30 percent over the two-year period, compared with growth of less than 10 percent for sales inside the euro area.


Periphery-Merchandise-Exports


    Discussions of external adjustment in the periphery often stress the need to improve external competitiveness. Unfortunately, competitiveness measures are at best imperfect. A common metric is based on unit labor costs, that is, on labor compensation growth relative to labor productivity. The intuition is simple: Higher wages erode competitiveness unless offset by productivity gains. However, this measure can be misleading in turbulent times. The shutdown of low-productivity firms boosts the economy’s average productivity, but does not mean that competitiveness has improved at surviving firms. Economy-wide unit labor cost measures can be particularly misleading when downturns are concentrated in low-productivity sectors such as construction. For example, much of the measured decline in Spain’s unit labor costs over the past several years owes to the country’s construction crash.

    The Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development calculates a measure of competitiveness based on export performance adjusted for the strength of trading partners’ economies. If exports grow more rapidly than trading partners’ total imports do, a country gains export market share; if exports grow more slowly, a country loses it.

    By this metric, Spain and Portugal have done well in recent years, with exports growing 6 to 8 percent faster than trading partners’ total imports from 2010 to 2012. (These figures are based on preliminary estimates from late 2012.) This matches up well with Germany’s performance of exports, which grew 5 percent faster than trading partners’ total imports. Italian exports, in contrast, just kept pace with imports in destination markets. Meanwhile, Greece lost substantial market share, with exports growing 10 percent more slowly than destination market imports did over the period.

    Import weakness also contributed to the external adjustment in the periphery. This was particularly true in Greece and Portugal, where purchases of foreign goods and services dropped 11 percent and 4 percent, respectively, from 2010 to 2012. Italy’s imports rose modestly, while Spain’s rose 6 percent. In all cases, import growth fell far short of export growth, helping to reduce external borrowing.

    Ongoing economic downturns have been the key driver of import weakness in the periphery. Indeed, import spending remains well below levels prevailing before the Great Recession; import spending in Germany, in contrast, has moved well above it pre-recession level. One concern is that periphery import spending might pick up quite strongly once economies recover, bringing a new round of large current account deficits. A more positive take is that the difficult adjustments have brought imports in line with exports; going forward, the two can grow together without the need for new borrowing.


Spending and Income

A current account deficit means that domestic spending is greater than domestic income. An alternative but equivalent measure of this gap is the difference between domestic investment and domestic saving. (Note that a country’s public and private spending goes either to consumption or investment, while income not spent on current consumption is by definition saved. Thus, the gap between spending and income is equal to investment spending minus saving. This same accounting logic means that a country’s fiscal deficit is the difference between government saving and investment spending.) The table below shows that much of the narrowing in periphery current account deficits over the past two years has come from lower investment spending, with declines equal to almost 2 percentage points of GDP to more than 4 percentage points. Higher saving also contributed to reduced current account deficits, with small increases in Italy and Spain and more substantial increases in Greece and Portugal.


Saving,-Investment-and-External-Balance


    The drop in investment spending, particularly outside the housing sector, could limit improvement in periphery competitiveness and growth prospects. As the next chart shows, this is especially the case since the recent drop in investment comes on the heels of an already large drop in 2008 and 2009—during the Great Recession but before the euro area crisis took hold. In contrast, investment spending in Germany has seen no pullback. Notably, economic recoveries are often led by investment spending. One risk for the periphery, then, is that stronger growth could see current account deficits widening as investment spending is again financed by external borrowing. On the positive side, stronger growth would also help boost public and private saving by limiting government budget deficits and raising corporate profits.


Periphery-Real-Fixed-Investment-Spending


Conclusion
Periphery countries have suffered painful contractions weaning themselves from foreign borrowing. The hope now is that the restoration of external balance in these countries will set the stage for meaningful recoveries. The debt burden from past borrowing remains, however, and argues for caution about the periphery outlook. Much will depend on the behavior of external investors. A further pullback would force periphery countries to lower spending below incomes to generate current account surpluses to pay down (rather than merely service) accumulated external debts. This would suggest an even steeper drop in periphery consumption and living standards. Recent balance-of-payments data have been encouraging on that point, however, as private investors stopped pulling money out of periphery countries in the second half of 2012, apparently reassured by the European Central Bank’s Outright Monetary Transaction program that was announced last August.


Disclaimer
The views expressed in this post are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the position of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York or the Federal Reserve System. Any errors or omissions are the responsibility of the authors.





  Higgins_matthew
Matthew Higgins is a vice president in the Federal Reserve Bank of New York’s Emerging Markets and International Affairs Group.


  Klitgaard_thomas
Thomas Klitgaard
is a vice president in the Bank’s Research and Statistics Group.

No comments: